Автор работы: Пользователь скрыл имя, 13 Мая 2010 в 18:44, Не определен
Экономический текст на английском языке с переводом, отчётом и пересказом
Throughout history, every society has faced the fundamental economic problem of deciding what to produce, and for whom, in a world of limited resources. In the 20th century, two competing economic systems, broadly speaking, have provided very different answers: command economies directed by a centralized government, and market economies based on private enterprise. Today, in the last decade of the 20th century, it is clear that, for people throughout the world, the central, command economy model has failed to sustain economic growth, to achieve a measure of prosperity, or even to provide economic security for its citizens.
HUMAN RESOURCE MANAGEMENT
"Motivation:
Reward system and the role of compensation"
The design and management of reward systems present the general manager with one of the most
difficult HRM tasks. This HRM policy area contains the greatest contradictions between the promise
of theory and the reality of implementation. Consequently, organizations sometimes go through cycles
of innovation and hope as reward systems are developed, followed by disillusionment as these reward
systems fail to deliver.
Rewards and employee satisfaction
Gaining an employee's satisfaction with the rewards given is not a simple matter. Rather, it is a function
of several factors that organizations
must learn to manage:
1. The individual's satisfaction with rewards is, in part, related to what is expected and how much is
received. Feelings of satisfaction or dissatisfaction arise when individuals compare their input - job
skills, education, effort, and performance - to output - the mix of extrinsic and intrinsic rewards they
receive.
2. Employee satisfaction is also affected by comparisons with other people in similar jobs and
organizations. In effect, employees compare their own input/output ratio with that of others. People
vary considerably in how they weigh various inputs in that comparison. They tend to weigh their strong
points more heavily, such as certain skills or a recent incident of effective performance. Individuals
also tend to overrate their own performance compared with the rating they receive from their
supervisors. The problem of unrealistic self-rating exists partly because supervisors in most
organizations do not communicate a candid evaluation of their subordinates' performance to them.
Such candid communication to subordinates, unless done skillfully, seriously risks damaging their
self-esteem. The bigger dilemma, however, is that failure by managers to communicate a candid
appraisal of performance makes it difficult for employees to develop a realistic view of their own
performance, thus increasing
the possibility of dissatisfaction with the pay they are receiving.
3. Employees often misperceive the rewards of others; their misperception can cause the employees
to become dissatisfied. Evidence shows that individuals tend to overestimate the pay of fellow
workers doing similar jobs and to underestimate their performance (a defense of self-esteem-building
mechanism). Misperceptions of the performance and rewards of others also occur because
organizations do not generally make available accurate information about the salary or performance of
others.
4. Finally, overall satisfaction results from a mix of rewards rather than from any single reward. The
evidence suggests that intrinsic rewards and extrinsic rewards are both important and that they cannot
be directly substituted for each other. Employees who are paid well for repetitious, boring work will
be dissatisfied with the lack of intrinsic rewards, just as employees paid poorly for interesting,
challenging work may be dissatisfied
with extrinsic rewards.
Rewards and motivation
From the organization's point of view, rewards are intended to motivate certain behaviors. But under
what conditions will rewards actually motivate employees? To be useful, rewards must be seen as
timely and tied to effective performance.
One theory suggests that the
following conditions are necessary for employee motivation.
1. Employees must believe effective performance (or certain specified behavior) will lead to certain
rewards. For example, attaining
certain results will lead to a bonus or approval from others.
2. Employees must feel that the rewards offered are attractive. Some employees may desire
promotions because they seek power, but others may want a fringe benefit, such as a pension,
because they are older and
want retirement security.
3. Employees must believe a certain level of individual effort will lead to achieving the corporation's
standards of performance.
As indicated, motivation to exert effort is triggered by the prospect of desired rewards: money,
recognition, promotion, and so forth. If effort leads to performance and performance leads to desired
rewards, the employee is satisfied and motivated to perform again.
As mentioned above, rewards fall into two categories: extrinsic and intrinsic. Extrinsic rewards come
from the organization as money, perquisites, or promotions or from supervisors and coworkers as
recognition. Intrinsic rewards accrue from performing the task itself, and may include the satisfaction
of accomplishment or a sense of influence. The process of work and the individual's response to it
provide the intrinsic rewards. But the organization seeking to increase intrinsic rewards must provide a
work environment that allows these satisfactions to occur; therefore, more organizations are
redesigning work and delegating
responsibility to enhance employee involvement.
Equity and participation
The ability of a reward system both to motivate and to satisfy depends on who influences and/or
controls the system's design and implementation. Even though considerable evidence suggests that
participation in decision making can lead to greater acceptance of decisions, participation in the design
and administration of reward systems is rare. Such participation is time-consuming.
Perhaps, a greater roadblock is that pay has been of the last strongholds of managerial prerogatives.
Concerned about employee self-interest and compensation costs, corporations do not typically allow
employees to participate in pay-system design or decisions. Thus, it is not possible to test thoroughly
the effects of widespread participation
on acceptance of and trust in reward system.
Compensation systems: the dilemmas
of practice
A body of experience, research and theory has been developed about how money satisfies and
motivates employees. Virtually every study on the importance of pay compared with other potential
rewards has shown that pay is important. It consistently ranks among the top five rewards. The
importance of pay and other rewards, however, is affected by many factors. Money, for example, is
likely to be viewed differently at various points in one's career, because the need for money versus
other rewards (status, growth, security, and so forth) changes at each stage. National culture is
another important factor. American managers and employees apparently emphasize pay for individual
performance more than do their European or Japanese counterparts. European and Japanese
companies, however, rely more on slow promotions and seniority as well as some degree of
employment security. Even within a single culture, shifting national forces may alter people's needs for
money versus other rewards.
Companies have developed various compensation systems and practices to achieve pay satisfaction
and motivation. In manufacturing firms, payroll costs can run as high as 40% of sales revenues,
whereas in service organizations payroll costs can top 70%. General managers, therefore, take an
understandable interest in
payroll costs and how this money is spent.
The traditional view of managers and compensation specialists is that if the right system can be
developed, it will solve most problems. This is not a plausible assumption, because, there is no one
right answer or objective solution to what or how someone should be paid. What people will accept,
be motivated by, or perceive as fair is highly subjective. Pay is a matter of perceptions and values that
often generate conflict.
Management's influence on attitudes
toward money
Many organizations are caught up in a vicious cycle that they partly create. Firms often emphasize
compensation levels and a belief in individual pay for performance in their recruitment and internal
communications. This is likely to attract people with high needs for money as well as to heighten that
need in those already employed. Thus, the meaning employees attach to money is partly shaped by
management's views. If merit increases, bonuses, stock options, and perquisites are held out as valued
symbols of recognition and success, employees will come to see them in this light even more than they
might have perceived them at first. Having heightened money's importance as a reward, management
must then respond to employees who may demand more money or better pay-for-performance
systems.
Firms must establish a philosophy about rewards and the role of pay in the mix of rewards. Without
such a philosophy, the compensation practices that happen to be in place, for the reasons already
stated, will continue to shape employees' satisfactions, and those expectations will sustain the existing
practices. If money has been emphasized as an important symbol of success, that emphasis will
continue even though a compensation system with a slightly different emphasis might have equal
motivational value with fewer administrative problems and perhaps even lower cost. Money is
important, but its degree of importance is influenced by the type of compensation system and
philosophy that management
adopts.
Pay for performance
Some reasons why organizations pay their employees for performance are as follows:
under the right conditions,
a pay-for-performance system can motivate desired behavior.
a pay-for-performance system
can help attract and keep achievement-oriented individuals.
a pay-for-performance system can help to retain good performers while discouraging the poor
performers.
In the US, at least, many employees, both managers and workers, prefer a pay-for-performance
system, although white-collar workers are significantly more supportive of the notion than blue-collar
workers.
But there is a gap, and the evidence indicates a wide gap, between the desire to devise a
pay-for-performance system
and the ability to make such a system work.
The most important distinction among various pay-for-performance systems is the level of aggregation
at which performance is defined - individual, group, and organizationwide. Several
pay-for-performance systems
are summarized in the exhibit that follows.
Individual performance Group
performance Organizationwide
performance
Merit system
Piece rate
Executive bonus
Productivity incentive
Cost effectiveness
Profit sharing
Productivity-sharing
Historically, pay for performance has meant pay for individual performance. Piece-rate incentive
systems for production employees and merit salary increases or bonus plans for salaried employees
have been the dominant means of paying for performance. In the last decade, piece-rate incentive
systems have dramatically declined because managers have discovered that such systems result in
dysfunctional behavior, such as low cooperation, artificial limits on production and resistance to
changing standards. Similarly, more questions are being asked about individual bonus plans for
executives as top managers
discovered their negative effects.
Meanwhile, organizationwide incentive systems are becoming more popular, particularly because
managers are finding that they foster cooperation, which leads to productivity and innovation. To
succeed, however, these plans require certain conditions. A review of the key considerations for
designing a pay-for-performance plan and a discussion of the problems that arise when these
considerations are not observed
follow.
Individual pay for performance. The design of an individual pay-for performance system requires an
analysis of the task. Does the individual have control over the performance (result) that is to be
measured? Is there a significant effort-to-performance relationship? For motivational reasons already
discussed such a relationship must exist. Unfortunately, many individual bonus, commission, or
piece-rate incentive plans fall short in meeting this requirement. An individual may not have control
over a performance result, such as sales or profit, because that result is affected by economic cycles
or competitive forces beyond his or her control. Indeed, there are few outcomes in complex
organizations that are not dependent on other functions or individuals, fewer still that are not subject to
external factors.
Choosing an appropriate measure of performance on which to base pay is a related problem incurred
by individual bonus plans. For reasons discussed earlier, effectiveness on a job can include many
facets not captured by cost, units produced, or sales revenues. Failure to include all activities that are
important for effectiveness can lead to negative consequences. For example, sales personnel who
receive a bonus for sales volume may push unneeded products, thus damaging long-term customer
relations, or they may push an unprofitable mix of products just to increase volume. These same
salespeople may also take orders and make commitments that cannot be met by manufacturing.
Instead, why not hold salespeople responsible for profits, a more inclusive measure of performance?
The obvious problem with this
measure is that sales personnel do not have control over profits.
These dilemmas constantly encountered and have led to the use of more subjective but inclusive
behavioral measures of performance. Why not observe if the salesperson or executive is performing
all aspects of the job well? More merit salary increases are based on subjective judgments and so are
some individual bonus plans. Subjective evaluation systems though they can be all-inclusive if based
on a thorough analysis of the job, require deep trust in management, good manager-subordinate
relations, and effective interpersonal skills. Unfortunately, these conditions are not fully met in many
situations, though they can
be developed if judged to be sufficiently important.
Group and organizationwide pay plans. Organizational effectiveness depends on employee
cooperation in most instances. An organization may elect to tie pay, or at least some portion of pay,
indirectly to individual performance. Seeking to foster team-work, a company may tie an incentive to
some measure of group performance, or it may offer some type of profits or productivity-sharing plan
for the whole plant or company.
Gains-sharing plans have been used for years in many varieties. The real power of a gains-sharing plan
comes when it is supported by a climate of participation. Various structures, systems, and processes
involve employees in decisions that improve the organization's performance and result in a bonus
throughout the organization.
Russian management's approach
to motivation.
Nowadays, top managers at Russian companies don't pay much attention to the employee motivation.